Glasgow City Council Housing Stock Transfer
University of Paisley Faculty of Business
Prepared by Professor Mike Danson, Iain Fleming,
Karen Gilmore, Andy Sternberg, Geoff Whittam
21 December 1999
Commissioned by UNISON
BACKGROUND & ECONOMIC ISSUES AND HOUSING DEVELOPMENTS
Index | Introduction | Financial
Aspects and Statutory Responsibilities
BACKGROUND
Although the initial proposal from UNISON was to conduct a critique
of the HACAS feasibility study, subsequent actions by the Scottish
Executive may have made much of this approach redundant. With the
introduction of a Steering Group, under the co-chair of the Minister
of the Communities, and an associated Development Team under the
direction of Bob Allan, the effective leadership of discussions
of a proposed stock transfer has been removed from the control of
the Council. The assumptions made about the timing, nature and form
of the process have been undermined, therefore, with a new set of
criteria in place. Speculation suggests that the Minister has rejected
the HACAS report, preferring instead to commission Ernst & Young
to undertake a new feasibility study.
Although no information has been made available on this new study,
including the cost of these consultants, many of the fundamental
flaws and lessons from the HACAS proposals will apply in this case,
but more strongly. The apparent steer from the government to promote
the rejected options based on a large number of community based
housing associations(CBHA's) will build in; the loss of economies
of scale in management, the loss of the use of a single DLO, and
the incurring of such additional costs as VAT on building services.
The following report has been written in some ignorance, therefore,
with significant gaps in our knowledge due to a lack of access to
the full feasibility studies, to the foundations of the assumptions
made in these and derived from the City Council, potential funders
and the Government, and to the short timescale. Nevertheless, despite
these limitations and qualifications, we believe that the conclusions
of the analysis are sufficiently robust to confirm the concerns
of UNISON, tenants and others. We question the entire concept of
stock transfer to a non-Council body. In summary, the proposals
are bad for the tenants, council taxpayers, and workers of Glasgow
City, and for Scotland as a whole. We argue this in terms of the
economic, financial and employment effects, but also because stock
transfer will be detrimental to the social inclusion and democratic
agendas this Executive promotes. The mechanics of the proposed transfer
appear to have been ignored in favour of a final solution. At this
stage, it appears as if Glasgow will have to accept the so-called
'community based housing associations' model if its debt burden
is to be reduced, regardless of the disruption and costs of establishing
this form of management.
The significant questions raised cannot be answered definitively
here as the Council and Scottish Executive have been secretive over
their own research. As the devil will undoubtedly be in the detail
in what is proposed, these are the critical underpinnings that the
tenants and workforce need to scrutinise if they are to be included
in the development of policy and to make informed judgements. That
they are not being informed, indeed they are not being involved
at all, is of great concern and confirms the suspicions that all
is not what it seems.
SUMMARY
1. The HACAS study has been overtaken by the establishment of the
Scottish Executive led Steering Group and the associated Development
Team.
2. We have analysed the HACAS report to the extent that we have
details on its assumptions, workings and findings.
3. Despite this, the analysis here suggests that new models of transfer
suggested by the Minister compared with the whole stock transfer
option preferred by HACAS, will undoubtedly be more expensive, lead
to greater job losses and not demonstrate any appreciable benefits
to tenants.
It is therefore even more vital that the details of the Ernst Young
and all other relevant reports are open to public scrutiny and debate.
If the tenants of Glasgow are to make an informed choice on the
options being presented then this is the minimum required.
ECONOMIC ISSUES AND HOUSING DEVELOPMENTS
All available evidence indicates that with demographic changes over
the next two decades there will be an increase in demand for affordable
good quality housing in the United Kingdom. For example, in Autumn
1995, the House of Commons Environment Select Committee along with
the Government itself produced a new set of figures which revealed
that 4.4 million new households are expected to emerge. The Department
of Environment projected that somewhere between 60,000 and 100,000
new homes would be required, each year over a similar time period,
for those emerging households who could not be expected to purchase
homes on the open market, that is, 'social affordable homes'. If
the backlog of unmet needs is included this figure rises to 120,000
per annum, 140,000 including Scotland and Wales, according to the
Chartered Institute of Housing. Although the population of Glasgow
is expected to continue to decline, underinvestment in housing in
the past and future net household formation mean that even here
there is a need for new housing. Indeed, Glasgow Regeneration is
proposing significant new 'villages' in Ruchill and elsewhere in
the city to meet this need.
For England, the DoE committed itself to working towards the lower
end of this projection, 60,000 homes. This figure, though, includes
what is described as new social lettings, which includes schemes
which encourage tenants to buy existing properties on the open market.
However, although even this commitment was undermined by the cutting
of investment in new social housing in the 1996 budget, the new
government has announced increased planned investment in housing
in England, with an extra £3.9 billion proposed for the next
three years.
For Scotland, the Scottish Executive has budgeted for an increase
in spending on housing from £558.5 million in 1998/99 to £576.7
million in 2001/02. Although this appears to represent an expansion
of 3.2%, these figures do not take account of inflation and so suggest
a decline in total expenditure. This contrasts starkly with the
position in England.
To compound this picture of underinvestment in new stock of social
affordable housing we find further cuts and underinvestment in repairs.
Stock surveys conducted in preparation for Large Scale Voluntary
Transfer indicate that the backlog of disrepair in the local authority
sector is at least £20 billion and expanding by a £1
billion per year across the country. To date selling council houses
has generated more revenues than selling off public utilities, but
unlike other privatisations the housing has to be replaced.
It is against this background that we find the Government solution,
attempting to be introduced in Glasgow, namely stock transfer.
The first stage in the process of addressing these problems was
the Community Housing Trust Feasibility Study (the study) which
identifies the following as beneficial to whole stock transfer in
Glasgow. All of these are contentious and open to challenge:
full modernisation of all the Council's housing stock which has
a long term life
stable and affordable rents for tenants
more community involvement and tenant control of service delivery
transfer of responsibility for the Council's Housing Revenue Account
(HRA) debt from tenants to the Government, and
continuity of employment on current terms and conditions for Council
staff.
The fundamental reasons underpinning the proposed stock transfer
are financial. Past housing investment decisions taken by successive
Glasgow city councils, sanctioned and supported by successive Westminster
governments, have left a legacy of poor housing and a large public
debt. Any history of social housing anywhere in the world inevitably
will return to a consideration of the position in Glasgow and Clydeside,
starting in the early years of this century. The Rent Strikes of
1915 through other forms of social and economic unrest have stimulated
various reactions by local and central governments. Progressively
over this century, Glasgow has embarked on revolutionary changes
to solve its massive housing problems.
With an extremely high level of overcrowding and congestion in the
period up to and including the first world war, with one million
people living in three square miles, there has always been a pressure
to improve the basic accommodation of the population of the city
on a very large scale. The garden suburbs of the inter-war years
failed to rehouse the vast majority of Glasgow's residents, yet
these first moves into social housing did suggest that a better
life could have been provided for all. The depression, indebtedness
and underinvestment meant that there were still horrendous housing
problems after the second world war, with one in seven of the Scottish
population living in the same crowded city.
The creation of the New Towns around Glasgow and the establishment
of the peripheral estates offered a way to address these levels
of deprivation and overcrowding. However, selective residential
policies by the New Towns and gross underinvestment in Castlemilk,
Pollok, Drumchapel and Easterhouse in housing and other social facilities
meant that the repeated cycles of despair were generated. Massive
economic dislocation caused by the decline of Glasgow's traditional
industries exacerbated these problems to a high degree. Instead
of comprehensive remedial action over the years, the fundamental
basis of the regional economy was allowed to decay. Housing was
then to be addressed with the next cheap solution: the multistorey
building. Again early examples were promising but the longer term
reality was for further underinvestment. In each and every turn,
the government offered a panacea only to undermine the vision and
the population's confidence with short-term cutbacks in programmes
and levels of investment.
This history of bad private landlordism, failed local and central
government plans and promises, and increasingly technocratic solutions
to the massive housing problems have left a legacy of debt and distrust
for quick-fix managerial strategies. Progressive cycles in Glasgow
and Clydeside housing of grand plans, underinvestment and structural
deterioration have been exaggerated by industrial decline and suburbanisation.
The relative quality of city housing has not closed on the UK average
over this century. Yet rents and public sector housing debt have
continued to increase.
By 1999, the debt on Scottish council housing amounts to some £4
billion, for Glasgow, the total debt is £920m. The current
housing stock numbers 94,000, so that unit debt is approximately
£9,800 (£9,787). Just to service this debt costs council
tenants 47% or £106.5m of the total housing revenue account
income. It has been suggested that freeing the tenant and council
of this debt would solve the financial problems of the authorities
and allow increased investment. The origins of this debt are important
to the understanding the critique of the feasibility study.
This debt is the result of Council borrowing rather than government
expenditure; it is in effect private borrowing from the market.
But, as the government guarantees the loans, the Treasury counts
this as part of the public sector borrowing requirement (PSBR) and
therefore controls this, apparently for macroeconomic demand management
reasons. To maintain the confidence of the City (of London) in the
Chancellor, Glasgow must pay the price of control of its ability
to borrow for even basic housing improvement. As explained above,
the debt arose out of past investment decisions. Many of these have
been questioned subsequently, witness the criticisms of the peripheral
schemes Castlemilk, Drumchapel, Easterhouse and Pollok, system built
solutions such as Queen Elizabeth Court, other high rise developments
and Darnley/Hutchie E. These account for much of the debt.
The nature of the debt is dependent on the scheduling and terms
agreed when the loans were secured. Periods of high inflation in
the 1960s and 70s could have led to interest rates of 15% being
fixed for 60 years. The switch to modernisation programmes rather
than new-build in the later decades increased the debt further.
The attempts to avoid the public funding crisis of the mid-1980s
through 'off the balance sheet' investments exacerbated the debt
problems even further.
The scheduling and terms of this debt are critical to the assumptions
underpinning the problems of servicing and of the alternative stock
proposals. Without access to these details, the choice being offered
to tenants and the potential to pursue alternative strategies are
restricted.
It is important to note that, unlike previous 'writing-off' of the
debt for Scottish Homes, the present exercise is not effectively
a debt 'write-off' for the Council. Rather the Council is being
offered a temporary servicing of the debt by the Scottish Executive.
The terms of how this debt will be serviced are still to be confirmed.
As the New Housing Partnerships - the apparent source for the servicing
- will have a budget of only £120 million in 2001/02 (Spending
Plans for Scotland, Scottish Executive, 11/99); although the Scottish
Office was planning on spending £160m in 2001/02 in February
1999), there is a question over how much of the debt will be taken
over by the Scottish Executive. If all the budget of the New Housing
Partnerships is to be devoted to the servicing of Glasgow's debt,
then there is a problem for other areas. Also, there is no guarantee
that this servicing will continue beyond the initial period. Glasgow
City Council could face the return of the debt burden, therefore,
with no rental flow to cover this. The Council Taxpayers would then
have to absorb this burden; in effect, given the poverty of most
tenants and their dependence on welfare benefits, the cost of servicing
will have been passed from housing benefit to council tax benefit.
The latter, however, only covers up to 80% of the tax whereas housing
benefit can cover up to a maximum of 100% of the costs; a more regressive
tax-benefit system would have been imposed into the financing of
Glasgow housing. That changes are being mooted for housing benefit
also will shift even more of the cost of supporting Glasgow's poor
onto the poor themselves.
As a consequence of the Comprehensive Spending Review, the recent
growth of public expenditure on health and education at the expense
of housing is projected to continue. Fiona Hyslop of the SNP has
argued that "At 1999 prices, the capital programme in Scotland's
council housing had fallen from £687m in 1989/90 to an estimated
£312m in 1999/2000." Much of the attention in the 1990s
on housing has been towards debt and rent levels, rather than quality.
Compounding this, UK government restrictions and real cuts in public
expenditure in Scotland as a consequence of the application of the
Barnett Formula are leading to an 8% cut over the first three years
of the new Parliament's life. A realistic appraisal of the power
balance between local authorities and Holyrood suggests that the
former will be expected to bear a disproportionate share of these
cuts.
It is also noteworthy that in February 1999 the Scottish Office
had provisionally earmarked £13m for the 'transfer feasibility
and option appraisal' of Glasgow's housing stock ('New Housing Partnerships
- 1999-2002. Report of Advisory Group', Scottish Office, February
1999). This not insignificant sum was not to be spent on housing,
on keeping rents affordable, on eradicating dampness, etc., but
on consultants.
In line with wider government policies throughout the 1990s, local
authorities are progressively being considered as enablers rather
than as providers of services. Glasgow City Council is seen, therefore,
as a strategic partner in a series of initiatives, as much to provide
an apparent degree of democratic legitimacy as to set, control or
influence the agenda. The recent strong criticism by community leaders
of the Glasgow Regeneration proposals partially to demolish Ruchill
and to replace it by a new extension of the West End are witness
to this manipulation of democratic control. Having to accept the
agendas of non-elected QUANGOs effectively reduces accountability
and the ability of local people to manage their own lives.
PSBR to GGFD
The preferred option outlined in the feasibility study is for whole
stock transfer. The suggested benefits of this are discussed elsewhere
in this critique. But the study itself notes that this option is
only considered given the current policy framework surrounding the
Public Sector Borrowing Requirement (PSBR). In the words of the
report: "It is the view of the independent advisers that without
a significant policy change by the Government relating to the Public
Sector Borrowing Requirement, whole stock transfer is the only way
the Council could achieve these benefits in the foreseeable future."
(page 7) It would appear that there are good reasons for the City
Council to spearhead a campaign to alter the composition of the
PSBR. Currently, the UK government is out of line with many of our
EU partners in including social housing in its PSBR figures. The
re-defining of the PSBR would therefore have other political and
economic advantages for the UK as a whole. This is a point made
clearly by Tony Blair in addressing the 1999 Labour Party Conference
regarding the need to release funds for investment: "And if
there are Treasury rules or antiquated concepts of public borrowing
that hold us back, change them. That is what intelligent government
is for."
UCATT, the STUC and others have argued for a changing of these Treasury
accounting rules. In particular, it is suggested that there are
strong reasons to support public borrowing where this will create
an income stream, or reduce expensive outflows to private sector
financial institutions, by investing in the social and economic
infrastructure, such as housing. Changing these rules to focus on
the General Government Financial Deficit (GGFD) rather than the
PSBR would bring the UK into line with the rest of Europe. The idea
of changing the Treasury rules in this way has been voiced by the
Labour Party for some time, as witnessed by the quote above from
the Prime Minister's first speech as party leader to a Labour Party
conference.
As argued by the STUC, the adoption of the GGFD would allow new
opportunities to open up to establish public corporations, such
as housing companies wholly owned by local authorities. This would
enable them to borrow from the market to fund projects where there
is a long-run commercial return without a consequent impact on the
public finances. Government reluctance to embrace this move to come
into line with the rest of the EU has been based on the fear that
it would signal to the markets that financial control was weakening.
It has been calculated that this change would have led to a 1998/99
deficit of but 0.25% of GDP. Indeed, recent statements by the Treasury
on the moves in public taxation and spending suggest a surplus would
have been achieved this year or next.
Overall UCATT has estimated that Council Housing is in profit. On
the back of this and given their size, local authorities should
be able to borrow in the market on more favourable terms than community,
voluntary sector or private housing companies. Historically, the
intervention of local authorities into the provision of housing
was to provide a good example to the private sector, and to avoid
paying excessive interest charges to the banks and other lenders.
The scale of council housing provision and of associated debt does
not negate the underlying argument over the legitimacy of the need
for change.
A further reason to reconsider the whole area of government debt
has been presented recently by the need of the pension funds and
life assurers to have access to investing in government bonds. These
are their safest form of long-term investment and are believed to
be critical in ensuring they have sufficient assets to meet future
pension commitments. The conservative fiscal regime adopted so vigorously
by the Chancellor has resulted in a reduction of such opportunities
for investment so that the Financial Times (for instance, 20/8/99)
amongst others has raised the need to expand the availability of
long-term gilts. These have a low rate of return: 'It is far cheaper
at present for the British government to borrow money over a 30-year
period than over 10 years' (FT 16/8/99), offering the opportunity
for much lower costs of borrowing for the public sector than the
privatised or housing company model.
In any event, the eagerness of the Westminster government and of
the Scottish Executive to pursue the stock transfer of social housing
is often predicated on the need to address perceived management
inefficiencies under council control. It is noteworthy that these
neither are identified nor improvements suggested in the HACAS feasibility
study. The suspicion is that with the same management structure
and the same senior managers, but with trades unions effectively
excluded and the debt removed initially from the backs of the new
organisations, the opportunity to make higher surpluses is being
created for these managers and their financial supporters. Arguments
over definitions of public borrowing and management inefficiencies
are secondary but useful distractions.
SUMMARY
1. There is a need to maintain the provision of affordable homes
for all in Glasgow.
2. The Scottish Executive is budgeting for further real cuts in
public investment in social housing.
3. Past under-investment means there is a massive repairs backlog.
4. The recommendations of the HACAS feasibility study to transfer
all Glasgow City Council's housing stock stem from financial considerations
rather than from identified management inefficiencies.
5. The proposal for a stock transfer threatens to be but the latest
in a long history of grand designs for Glasgow housing.
6. It is still unclear how the Scottish Executive intends to service
the housing debt and for how long, there are no guarantees. With
no promises to 'write-off' the debt, this uncertainty will continue.
7. A change by central government from PSBR to GGFD would benefit
the whole economy and the adoption of the GGFD would allow new opportunities
to open up to establish public housing corporations.
Index |Introduction | Financial
Aspects and Statutory Responsibilities
Submissions index | Home
|